Trading in pollution

OECD Observer

One way to deal with pollution is to encourage polluters to buy and sell limited rights or permits to pollute. It is a market that works, though improvements are needed.

A 50% fall in emissions over 10 years: this might sound like fantasy but is exactly what the United States Environmental Protection Agency’s Sulphur Dioxide (SO2) Program (the “Acid Rain” programme) achieved in the 1990s when it set up an “air market” of tradeable permits.

The programme, which came into force in 1995 following the Clean Air Act Amendments five years earlier, introduced flexibility into pre-existing regulations mandating the use of flue-gas desulphurisation for electricity-generating plants. Instead, it gave firms the right to determine their own compliance strategy, including the right to purchase tradeable emission permits from other firms.

In short, a cap on total sulphur dioxide emissions was set, and the total permits issued among firms generating sulphur dioxide was equal to this cap. Firms could then trade these permits among themselves: those firms generating more emissions than their initial allocation would buy permits from firms that generated fewer. The total number of permits would remain stable, but the distribution of permits among firms would change with the market.

This made the programme environmentally effective, as well as reassuring regulators and the public (including environmental NGOs), that total emissions would not exceed a certain limit. The system was also economically efficient, because high-cost abaters bought permits from those who could abate at lower

cost. And it encouraged managerial and technological innovation as emitting firms and others sought out the best ways to meet the regulatory requirements. Meanwhile, the installation of continuous monitoring devices by the firms themselves reduced the government’s administration and enforcement costs.

The test was in the results, of course. From emission levels of 10 million tonnes for affected units of SO2 in 1990, emissions fell to less than five million by the end of the decade. Moreover, this was achieved at much lower costs than had been anticipated: original estimates of permit prices in the first phase of the programme had ranged between US$181 and US$981, but actual prices have hovered around US$150 and have rarely been in excess of the lower band of estimates.

The Acid Rain programme is not an isolated case. Other successful efforts to introduce tradeable permits reduced lead in gasoline, cut ozone-depleting substances, and other pollutants, like oxides of nitrogen. Now, other countries are following the US example, with notable programmes for a variety of pollutants starting or in existence in Canada, Denmark, the Netherlands, the United Kingdom, and elsewhere.

Perhaps more importantly, the Kyoto Protocol has endorsed the use of tradeable permits on an international scale, as a means to address climate change. Indeed, it is paradoxical that the United States has refused to ratify a protocol which endorses an instrument that they have pioneered. Instead, the baton has been taken up by countries such as Denmark and the United Kingdom, who have developed tradeable permit programmes for carbon dioxide in anticipation of an EU-wide scheme.

However, not all tradeable permit systems have had similar success and many have resulted in few trades and precious few efficiency gains. This has been particularly true of the first American water pollution tradeable permit regimes. One reason for this is the fact that in some cases there were very few participants, since the scope of the market was determined by the affected river or lake. Moreover, those firms that were involved often had similar technological opportunities to reduce their effluent, so narrowing the scope to increase efficiency by trading permits. In addition, the first programmes often placed significant regulatory constraints on trading. Some have adopted fairly cumbersome systems, such as basing the creation of permits on emission reductions below an agreed baseline: The gap between the polluter’s improved performance and the baseline would become a permit, which they can then sell to others. Good in theory, but it demands paperwork, not least in trying to define the baseline.

The lessons are that tradeable permits markets should be broad to ensure competitiveness and enable efficiency gains. The rules should be easily understood to encourage participants to exploit the market as fully as possible. And while single undifferentiated markets appear to work for carbon dioxide emissions whose effects are widespread, markets for pollutants with different effects must take account of local “hot spots”.

Tradeable permits can work, but they are under-used by OECD country governments. This is part of the problem, since they need to be tried and tested more if they are to be improved. This is likely to happen in the years ahead. The EU carbon dioxide programme, which is expected to get under way in 2005, will be watched with interest.



• OECD (2002), Implementing Domestic Tradeable Permits: Recent Developments and Future Challenges, OECD, Paris.

• Ellerman, Denny et al (2000), Markets for Clean Air: The U.S. Acid Rain Program, Cambridge University Press, New York.

©OECD Observer No. 233, August 2002

Economic data


Stay up-to-date with the latest news from the OECD by signing up for our e-newsletter :

Twitter feed

Suscribe now

<b>Subscribe now!</b>

To receive your exclusive print editions delivered to you directly

Online edition
Previous editions

Don't miss

  • Africa's cities at the forefront of progress: Africa is urbanising at a historically rapid pace coupled with an unprecedented demographic boom. By 2050, about 56% of Africans are expected to live in cities. This poses major policy challenges, but make no mistake: Africa’s cities and towns are engines of progress that, if harnessed correctly, can fuel the entire continent’s sustainable development.
  • “Nizip” refugee camp visit
    July 2016: OECD Secretary-General Angel Gurría visits the “Nizip” refugee camp, situated between Gaziantep and the Turkish-Syrian border, accompanied by Turkey’s Deputy Prime Minister Mehmet Şimşek. The camp accommodates a small number of the 2.75 million Syrians currently registered in Turkey, mostly outside the camps. In his tour of the camp, Mr Gurría visits a school, speaks with refugees and gives a short interview.
  • OECD Observer i-Sheet Series: OECD Observer i-Sheets are smart contents pages on major issues and events. Use them to find current or recent articles, video, books and working papers. To browse on paper and read on line, or simply download.
  • Queen Maxima of the Netherlands gives a speech next to Mexico's President Enrique Pena Nieto (not pictured) during the International Forum of Financial Inclusion at the National Palace in Mexico City, Mexico June 21, 2016.
  • How sustainable is the ocean as a source of economic development? The Ocean Economy in 2030 examines the risks and uncertainties surrounding the future development of ocean industries, the innovations required in science and technology to support their progress, their potential contribution to green growth and some of the implications for ocean management.
  • OECD Environment Director Simon Upton presented a talk at Imperial College London on 21 April 2016. With the world awash in surplus oil and prices languishing around US$40 per barrel, how can governments step up efforts to transform the world’s energy systems in line with the Paris Agreement?
  • Happy 10th birthday to Twitter. This 2008 OECD Observer interview with Henry Copeland said you’d do well.
  • The OECD Gender Initiative examines existing barriers to gender equality in education, employment, and entrepreneurship. The gender portal monitors the progress made by governments to promote gender equality in both OECD and non-OECD countries and provides good practices based on analytical tools and reliable data.
  • Once migrants reach Europe, countries face integration challenge: OECD's Thomas Liebig speaks to NPR's Audie Cornish.

  • Message from the International Space Station to COP21

  • The carbon clock is ticking: OECD’s Gurría on CNBC

  • If we want to reach zero net emissions by the end of the century, we must align our policies for a low-carbon economy, put a price on carbon everywhere, spend less subsidising fossil fuels and invest more in clean energy. OECD at #COP21 – OECD statement for #COP21
  • They are green and local --It’s a new generation of entrepreneurs in Kenya with big dreams of sustainable energy and the drive to see their innovative technologies throughout Africa.
  • Pole to Paris Project
  • In order to face global warming, Asia needs at least $40 billion per year, derived from both the public and private sector. Read how to bridge the climate financing gap on the Asian Bank of Development's website.
  • How can cities fight climate change?
    Discover projects in Denmark, Canada, Australia, Japan and Mexico.
  • Climate: What's changed, what hasn't, what we can do about it.
    Lecture by OECD Secretary-General Angel Gurría, hosted by the London School of Economics and Aviva Investors in association with ClimateWise, London, UK, 3 July 2015.
  • Is technological progress slowing down? Is it speeding up? At the OECD, we believe the research from our Future of ‪Productivity‬ project helps to resolve this paradox.
  • Is inequality bad for growth? That redistribution boosts economies is not established by the evidence says FT economics editor Chris Giles. Read more on
  • Interested in a career in Paris at the OECD? The OECD is a major international organisation, with a mission to build better policies for better lives. With our hub based in one of the world's global cities and offices across continents, find out more at .

Most Popular Articles


What issue are you most concerned about in 2016?

Euro crisis
International conflict
Global warming

OECD Insights Blog

NOTE: All signed articles in the OECD Observer express the opinions of the authors
and do not necessarily represent the official views of OECD member countries.

All rights reserved. OECD 2016